en pl
en pl

Decyzje

Show issue
Year 6/2016 
Issue 26

Evolutionary stability of discriminating social norms

Katarzyna Abramczuk
Uniwersytet Warszawski

6/2016 (26) Decyzje

DOI 10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.77

Abstract

The paper presents an evolutionary model illustrating the dynamics that give rise to discriminatory social norms i.e. such rules of behaviour that fulfi l two conditions: (1) they treat differently actors having the same abilities and technical options, but differing in some arbitrary sense (2) they are supported by socially enforced sanctions. In the presented model both discrimination and social norms are necessary to solve a coordination problem that arises when the situation requires different actors to perform different tasks. The properties of behavioural rules relying on discrimination and leading to various degrees of inequality are analysed. It is demonstrated that in general norms ensuring equal payoffs are easier to stabilize, but unfair norms can also be stable.

References

  1. Abramczuk, K., Obłój, J. (in press). Third party sanctions in games with communication. Studies in Logic, Grammar and Rhetoric. [Google Scholar]
  2. Acker, J. (1988). Class, gender, and the relations of distribution. Signs, 13(3), 473-497. [Google Scholar]
  3. Anker, R. (1997). Theories of occupational segregation by sex: An overview. International Labour Review, 136, 315. [Google Scholar]
  4. Arrow, K.J.(1973). The theory of discrimination. In: Ashenfelter, O., Rees, A. (eds.) Discrimination in Labour Markets (pp. 3-33). Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ. [Google Scholar]
  5. Aumann, R.J. (1959). Acceptable points in general cooperative n-person games. Contributions to the Theory of Games (AM-40), 4, 287. [Google Scholar]
  6. Aumann, R.J. (1974). Subjectivity and correlation in randomized strategies. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1, 67-96. [Google Scholar]
  7. Axelrod, R.M. (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation. Basic Books, New York. [Google Scholar]
  8. Bar-Hillel, M. (1980). The base-rate fallacy in probability judgments. Acta Psychologica, 44(3), 211-233. [Google Scholar]
  9. Barron, R.D., Norris, G.M. (1991). Sexual divisions a nd the dual labour market. In: Leonard, D., Allen, S. (eds.) Sexual Divisions Revisited (pp. 153-177). Springer. [Google Scholar]
  10. Becker, G.S.(2009). Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. University of Chicago Press, pp. 24. [Google Scholar]
  11. Bendor, J., Swistak, P. (1998). Evolutionary equilibria: Characterization theorems and their implications. Theory and Decision, 45(2), 99-159. [Google Scholar]
  12. Bendor, J., Swistak, P. (2000). The impossibility of pure homo economicus. In: Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association. Marriott Wardman Park. [Google Scholar]
  13. Bendor, J., Swistak, P. (2001). The evolution of norms. American Journal of Sociology, 106(6), 1493-1545. [Google Scholar]
  14. Boyd, R., Lorberbaum, J.P. (1987). No pure strategy is evolutionarily stable in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma game. Nature, 327, 58-59. [Google Scholar]
  15. Boyd, R., Richerson, P.J. (1989). The evolution of indirect reciprocity. Social Network, 11, 213-36. [Google Scholar]
  16. Boyd, R., Richerson, P.J. (1992). Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethology and Sociobiology, 13(3), 171-195. [Google Scholar]
  17. Brines, J. (1993). The exchange value of housework. Rationality and Society, 5(3), 302-340. [Google Scholar]
  18. Crowley, P.H. (2000). Hawks, doves, and mixed-symmetry games. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 204(4), 543-563. [Google Scholar]
  19. Crowley, P.H. (2001). Dangerous games and the emergence of social structure: evolving memorybased strategies for the generalized hawk-dove game. Behavioral Ecology, 12(6), 753-760. [Google Scholar]
  20. Crowley, P.H., Cottrell, T., Garcia, T., Hatch, M., Sargent, R.C., Stokes, B.J., White, J.M. (1998). Solving the complementarity dilemma: evolving strategies for simultaneous hermaphroditism. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 195(1), 13-26. [Google Scholar]
  21. Dahrendorf, R. (1962). On the origin of social inequality. In: Laslett, P. (ed.) Philosophy, Politics and Society. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. [Google Scholar]
  22. Della Fave, L.R. (1980). The meek shall not inherit the earth: Self-evaluation and the legitimacy of stratication. American Sociological Review, 45(6), 955-971. [Google Scholar]
  23. Farrell, J., Ware, R. (1989). Evolutionary stability in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. Theoretical Population Biology 36(2), 161-166. [Google Scholar]
  24. Gaissmaier, W., Schooler, L.J. (2008). The smart potential behind probability matching. Cognition, 109(3), 416-422. [Google Scholar]
  25. Gal, I. (1996). Understanding repeated simple choices. Thinking & Reasoning 2(1), 81-98. [Google Scholar]
  26. Haugaard, M. (2003). Reections on seven ways of creating power. European Journal of Social Theory, 6(1), 87-113. [Google Scholar]
  27. Hayek, F.A. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. The University of Chicago, Chicago, pp. 25. [Google Scholar]
  28. Homans, G.C. (1950). The Human Group. Brace and Company. Harcourt. [Google Scholar]
  29. Ishida, J. (2003). The role of intrahousehold bargaining in gender discrimination. Rationality and Society, 15(3), 361-380. [Google Scholar]
  30. Kandori, M. (2002). Introduction to repeated games with private monitoring. Journal of Economic Theory, 102(1), 1-15. [Google Scholar]
  31. Kaneko, M., Matsui, A. (1999). Inductive game theory: discrimination and prejudices. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 1(1), 101-137. [Google Scholar]
  32. Kilbourne, B.S., England, P., Farkas, G., Beron, K., Weir, D. (1994). Returns to skill, compensating differentials, and gender bias: Effects of occupational characteristics on the wages of white women and men. American Journalof Sociology, 100(3), 689-719. [Google Scholar]
  33. Lippert, S., Spagnolo, G. (2011). Networks of relations and word-of-mouth communication. Games and Economic Behavior, 72(1), 202-217. [Google Scholar]
  34. Lorberbaum, J. (1994). No strategy is evolutionarily stable in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 168(2), 117-130. [Google Scholar]
  35. McDonald, G.W. (1980). Family power: The assessment of a decade of theory and research, 1970-1979. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 841-854. [Google Scholar]
  36. McElreath, R., Boyd, R., Richerson, P.J. (2003). Shared norms and the evolution of ethnic markers. Current Anthropology, 44(1), 122-130. [Google Scholar]
  37. Nowak, M., Sigmund, K. (1998). The dynamics of indirect reciprocity. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 194(4), 561-74. [Google Scholar]
  38. Nowak, M., Sigmund, K. (1998). Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature, 393, 573-577. [Google Scholar]
  39. Nowak, M.A. (2006). Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science, 314(5805), 1560-1563. [Google Scholar]
  40. Okuno-Fujiwara, M., Postlewaite, A. (1995). Social norms and random matching games. Games and Economic Behavior 9(1), 79-109. [Google Scholar]
  41. Phelps, E.S. (1972). The statistical theory of racism and sexism. The American Economic Review, 62(4), 659-661. [Google Scholar]
  42. Ponti, G., Seymour, R.M. (1999). Evolutionary stability of inequality structures. Rationality and Society, 11(1), 47-77. [Google Scholar]
  43. Quint, T., Shubik, M. (2001). Games of status. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 3(4), 349-372. [Google Scholar]
  44. Raub, W., Weesie, J. (1990). Reputation and efficiency in social interactions: An example of network effects. American Journal of Sociology, 96, 626-654. [Google Scholar]
  45. Reichenbach, H. (1971). The Theory of Probability. University of California Press, pp. 26. [Google Scholar]
  46. Rothbart, M., Taylor, M. (1992). Category labels and social reality: Do we viewsocial categories as natural kinds? In: Fiedler, K. (ed.) Language, Interaction and Social Cognition (pp. 11-36). Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA. [Google Scholar]
  47. Sudgen, R. (1986). The Economics of Rights. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. [Google Scholar]
  48. Tversky, A., Kahneman, D. (1983). Extensional versus intuitive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy in probability judgment. Psychological review, 90(4), 293. [Google Scholar]
  49. Ullmann-Margalit, E. (2015). The Emergence of Norms. Oxford University Press, USA. [Google Scholar]
  50. Wagenaar, W.A. (1972). Generation of random sequences by human subjects: A critical survey of literature. Psychological Bulletin, 77(1), 65. [Google Scholar]
  51. Weibull, J.W. (1997). Evolutionary Game Theory. MIT press. [Google Scholar]
  52. Youm, Y., Laumann, E.O. (2003). The effect of structural embeddedness on the division of household labor: A game-theoretic model using a network approach. Rationality and Society, 15(2), 243-280. [Google Scholar]

Full metadata record

Cite this record

APA style

Abramczuk, Katarzyna (2016). Evolutionary stability of discriminating social norms. (2016). Evolutionary stability of discriminating social norms. Decyzje, (26), 27-57. https://doi.org/ 10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.77 (Original work published 6/2016AD)

MLA style

Abramczuk, Katarzyna. “Evolutionary Stability Of Discriminating Social Norms”. 6/2016AD. Decyzje, no. 26, 2016, pp. 27-57.

Chicago style

Abramczuk, Katarzyna. “Evolutionary Stability Of Discriminating Social Norms”. Decyzje, Decyzje, no. 26 (2016): 27-57. doi: 10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.77.