en pl
en pl

Decyzje

Zobacz wydanie
Rok 6/2016 
Numer 26

Ewolucyjna stabilność dyskryminujących norm społecznych

Katarzyna Abramczuk
Uniwersytet Warszawski

6/2016 (26) Decyzje

DOI 10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.77

Abstrakt

Praca przedstawia model ewolucyjny ilustrujący mechanizmy przyczyniające się do stabilności dyskryminujących norm społecznych, tj. zasad zachowania spełniających dwa warunki: (1) odmienne traktowanie aktorów o tych samych umiejętnościach i możliwościach, ale różniących się arbitralnymi cechami, (2) wsparcie na sankcjach społecznych. W proponowanym modelu zarówno dyskryminacja, jak i normy społeczne są konieczne, by rozwiązać problem koordynacji powstający, gdy sytuacja wymaga, aby poszczególni aktorzy podjęli różne zadania. Analizowane są własności zasad zachowania opartych na dyskryminacji, skutkujących różnymi poziomami nierówności. Pokazano, że
w ogólności zasady zapewniające równe wypłaty są łatwiejsze do ustabilizowania, ale niesprawiedliwe normy także mogą być stabilne.

Powiązania

  1. Abramczuk, K., Obłój, J. (in press). Third party sanctions in games with communication. Studies in Logic, Grammar and Rhetoric. [Google Scholar]
  2. Acker, J. (1988). Class, gender, and the relations of distribution. Signs, 13(3), 473-497. [Google Scholar]
  3. Anker, R. (1997). Theories of occupational segregation by sex: An overview. International Labour Review, 136, 315. [Google Scholar]
  4. Arrow, K.J.(1973). The theory of discrimination. In: Ashenfelter, O., Rees, A. (eds.) Discrimination in Labour Markets (pp. 3-33). Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ. [Google Scholar]
  5. Aumann, R.J. (1959). Acceptable points in general cooperative n-person games. Contributions to the Theory of Games (AM-40), 4, 287. [Google Scholar]
  6. Aumann, R.J. (1974). Subjectivity and correlation in randomized strategies. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1, 67-96. [Google Scholar]
  7. Axelrod, R.M. (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation. Basic Books, New York. [Google Scholar]
  8. Bar-Hillel, M. (1980). The base-rate fallacy in probability judgments. Acta Psychologica, 44(3), 211-233. [Google Scholar]
  9. Barron, R.D., Norris, G.M. (1991). Sexual divisions a nd the dual labour market. In: Leonard, D., Allen, S. (eds.) Sexual Divisions Revisited (pp. 153-177). Springer. [Google Scholar]
  10. Becker, G.S.(2009). Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. University of Chicago Press, pp. 24. [Google Scholar]
  11. Bendor, J., Swistak, P. (1998). Evolutionary equilibria: Characterization theorems and their implications. Theory and Decision, 45(2), 99-159. [Google Scholar]
  12. Bendor, J., Swistak, P. (2000). The impossibility of pure homo economicus. In: Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association. Marriott Wardman Park. [Google Scholar]
  13. Bendor, J., Swistak, P. (2001). The evolution of norms. American Journal of Sociology, 106(6), 1493-1545. [Google Scholar]
  14. Boyd, R., Lorberbaum, J.P. (1987). No pure strategy is evolutionarily stable in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma game. Nature, 327, 58-59. [Google Scholar]
  15. Boyd, R., Richerson, P.J. (1989). The evolution of indirect reciprocity. Social Network, 11, 213-36. [Google Scholar]
  16. Boyd, R., Richerson, P.J. (1992). Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethology and Sociobiology, 13(3), 171-195. [Google Scholar]
  17. Brines, J. (1993). The exchange value of housework. Rationality and Society, 5(3), 302-340. [Google Scholar]
  18. Crowley, P.H. (2000). Hawks, doves, and mixed-symmetry games. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 204(4), 543-563. [Google Scholar]
  19. Crowley, P.H. (2001). Dangerous games and the emergence of social structure: evolving memorybased strategies for the generalized hawk-dove game. Behavioral Ecology, 12(6), 753-760. [Google Scholar]
  20. Crowley, P.H., Cottrell, T., Garcia, T., Hatch, M., Sargent, R.C., Stokes, B.J., White, J.M. (1998). Solving the complementarity dilemma: evolving strategies for simultaneous hermaphroditism. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 195(1), 13-26. [Google Scholar]
  21. Dahrendorf, R. (1962). On the origin of social inequality. In: Laslett, P. (ed.) Philosophy, Politics and Society. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. [Google Scholar]
  22. Della Fave, L.R. (1980). The meek shall not inherit the earth: Self-evaluation and the legitimacy of stratication. American Sociological Review, 45(6), 955-971. [Google Scholar]
  23. Farrell, J., Ware, R. (1989). Evolutionary stability in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. Theoretical Population Biology 36(2), 161-166. [Google Scholar]
  24. Gaissmaier, W., Schooler, L.J. (2008). The smart potential behind probability matching. Cognition, 109(3), 416-422. [Google Scholar]
  25. Gal, I. (1996). Understanding repeated simple choices. Thinking & Reasoning 2(1), 81-98. [Google Scholar]
  26. Haugaard, M. (2003). Reections on seven ways of creating power. European Journal of Social Theory, 6(1), 87-113. [Google Scholar]
  27. Hayek, F.A. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. The University of Chicago, Chicago, pp. 25. [Google Scholar]
  28. Homans, G.C. (1950). The Human Group. Brace and Company. Harcourt. [Google Scholar]
  29. Ishida, J. (2003). The role of intrahousehold bargaining in gender discrimination. Rationality and Society, 15(3), 361-380. [Google Scholar]
  30. Kandori, M. (2002). Introduction to repeated games with private monitoring. Journal of Economic Theory, 102(1), 1-15. [Google Scholar]
  31. Kaneko, M., Matsui, A. (1999). Inductive game theory: discrimination and prejudices. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 1(1), 101-137. [Google Scholar]
  32. Kilbourne, B.S., England, P., Farkas, G., Beron, K., Weir, D. (1994). Returns to skill, compensating differentials, and gender bias: Effects of occupational characteristics on the wages of white women and men. American Journalof Sociology, 100(3), 689-719. [Google Scholar]
  33. Lippert, S., Spagnolo, G. (2011). Networks of relations and word-of-mouth communication. Games and Economic Behavior, 72(1), 202-217. [Google Scholar]
  34. Lorberbaum, J. (1994). No strategy is evolutionarily stable in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 168(2), 117-130. [Google Scholar]
  35. McDonald, G.W. (1980). Family power: The assessment of a decade of theory and research, 1970-1979. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 841-854. [Google Scholar]
  36. McElreath, R., Boyd, R., Richerson, P.J. (2003). Shared norms and the evolution of ethnic markers. Current Anthropology, 44(1), 122-130. [Google Scholar]
  37. Nowak, M., Sigmund, K. (1998). The dynamics of indirect reciprocity. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 194(4), 561-74. [Google Scholar]
  38. Nowak, M., Sigmund, K. (1998). Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature, 393, 573-577. [Google Scholar]
  39. Nowak, M.A. (2006). Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science, 314(5805), 1560-1563. [Google Scholar]
  40. Okuno-Fujiwara, M., Postlewaite, A. (1995). Social norms and random matching games. Games and Economic Behavior 9(1), 79-109. [Google Scholar]
  41. Phelps, E.S. (1972). The statistical theory of racism and sexism. The American Economic Review, 62(4), 659-661. [Google Scholar]
  42. Ponti, G., Seymour, R.M. (1999). Evolutionary stability of inequality structures. Rationality and Society, 11(1), 47-77. [Google Scholar]
  43. Quint, T., Shubik, M. (2001). Games of status. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 3(4), 349-372. [Google Scholar]
  44. Raub, W., Weesie, J. (1990). Reputation and efficiency in social interactions: An example of network effects. American Journal of Sociology, 96, 626-654. [Google Scholar]
  45. Reichenbach, H. (1971). The Theory of Probability. University of California Press, pp. 26. [Google Scholar]
  46. Rothbart, M., Taylor, M. (1992). Category labels and social reality: Do we viewsocial categories as natural kinds? In: Fiedler, K. (ed.) Language, Interaction and Social Cognition (pp. 11-36). Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA. [Google Scholar]
  47. Sudgen, R. (1986). The Economics of Rights. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. [Google Scholar]
  48. Tversky, A., Kahneman, D. (1983). Extensional versus intuitive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy in probability judgment. Psychological review, 90(4), 293. [Google Scholar]
  49. Ullmann-Margalit, E. (2015). The Emergence of Norms. Oxford University Press, USA. [Google Scholar]
  50. Wagenaar, W.A. (1972). Generation of random sequences by human subjects: A critical survey of literature. Psychological Bulletin, 77(1), 65. [Google Scholar]
  51. Weibull, J.W. (1997). Evolutionary Game Theory. MIT press. [Google Scholar]
  52. Youm, Y., Laumann, E.O. (2003). The effect of structural embeddedness on the division of household labor: A game-theoretic model using a network approach. Rationality and Society, 15(2), 243-280. [Google Scholar]

Kompletne metadane

Cytowanie zasobu

APA style

Abramczuk, Katarzyna (2016). Ewolucyjna stabilność dyskryminujących norm społecznych. (2016). Ewolucyjna stabilność dyskryminujących norm społecznych. Decyzje, (26), 27-57. https://doi.org/ 10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.77 (Original work published 6/2016n.e.)

MLA style

Abramczuk, Katarzyna. „Ewolucyjna Stabilność Dyskryminujących Norm Społecznych”. 6/2016n.e. Decyzje, nr 26, 2016, ss. 27-57.

Chicago style

Abramczuk, Katarzyna. „Ewolucyjna Stabilność Dyskryminujących Norm Społecznych”. Decyzje, Decyzje, nr 26 (2016): 27-57. doi: 10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.77.