en pl
en pl

Decyzje

Show issue
Year 12/2104 
Issue 24

The endogeneity of time preference and analysis of collective behavior

Marianna Klochko
The Ohio State University, Marion

12/2104 (24) Decyzje

DOI 10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.63

Abstract

This essay proposes that time preference is an essential component of analysis of collective behavior and provision of public goods. It addresses the validity of the assumption that time preference, as a parameter in individual utility functions, is exogenous and fi xed. While individual time discounting is used to predict many social phenomena, it is quite often applied in a fi xed form where the possibility of change is rarely discussed. The mechanism of change in individual time discounting is explored in different social contexts, using student, inmate and drug addict populations. This study establishes that certain parameters, such as the length of exposure to new environment and new social connections, are of extreme importance in determining the degree of change in time discounting.

References

  1. Ainslie, G. (1992). Picoeconomics: The Strategic Interaction of Successive Motivational States Within the Person. Cambridge. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  2. Ainslie, G, and V. Haendel. (1982). The Motives of the Will. In: Etiological Aspects of Alcohol and Drug Abuse. E. Gottheil, K.A. Druley, T.E. Skoloda, and H.M. Waxman, eds. Springfield, IL: Charles C. Thomas. [Google Scholar]
  3. Allen, Terry J., F. Gerard Moeller, Howard M. Rhoades, and Don R. Cherek. (1998). Impulsivity and History of Drug Dependence. Drug and Alcohol Dependence, 50, 137-145. [Google Scholar]
  4. Axelrod, Robert. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books. [Google Scholar]
  5. Aumann, Robert. (1959). Acceptable Points in General Cooperative n-person Games. In: Contributions to the Theory of Games, vol. IV. R. Duncan Luce and Albert W. Tucker, eds. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
  6. Becker, Gary S., and Kevin M. Murphy. (1988). A Theory of Rational Addiction. The Journal of Political Economy, 96(4), 675-700. [Google Scholar]
  7. Benzion, Uri, Amnon Rapoport and Joseph Yagil. (1989). Discount Rates Inferred from Decisions: An experimental Study. Management Science, 35(3), 270-84. [Google Scholar]
  8. Bickel, W. K., A. L.Odum, and G.J. Madden. (1999). Impulsivity and cigarette smoking: delay discounting in current, never, and ex-smokers. Psychopharmacology, 146(4), 447-454. [Google Scholar]
  9. Bretteville-Jensen, A.L. (1999). Addiction and Discounting. Journal of Health Economics, 18, 393-407. [Google Scholar]
  10. Chapman, Gretchen B. and Jennifer R. Winquist. (1998). The Magnitude Effect: Temporal Discount Rates and Restaurant Tips. Psychotomic Bulletin and Review, 5(1), 119-123. [Google Scholar]
  11. Clemmer, Donald. (1940). The Prison Community. Boston, MA: Christopher Publishing House. [Google Scholar]
  12. Davids, Anthony and Bradley B. Falkof. (1975). Juvenile delinquents then and now. Journal of Abnormal Psychology, 84(2), 161-64. [Google Scholar]
  13. Dawkins, R. (1976). The Selfish Gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  14. Elster, Jon. (1999). Strong Feelings: Emotion, Addiction, and Human Behavior. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
  15. Elster, Jon. (1992). Intertemporal Choice and Political Thought. In: Choice Over Time. George Loewenstein and Jon Elster, eds. New York, NY: Russel Sage Foundation. [Google Scholar]
  16. Frederick, Shane, George Lowenstein and Ted O’Donohue. (2002). Time discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351-401. [Google Scholar]
  17. Friedman, James W. (1971). A Non-cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames. Review of Economic Studies, 38, 1-12. [Google Scholar]
  18. Giordano, Louis A., Warren K. Bickel, George Loewenstein, Eric A. Jacobs, Lisa Marsch and Gary J. Badger. (2002). Mild Opioid Deprivation Increases the Degree that Opioid-dependent Outpatients Discount Delayed Heroin and Money. Psychopharmacology, 163, 174-182. [Google Scholar]
  19. Gottfredson, Michael R. and Travis Hirshi. (1990). A General Theory of Crime. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  20. Green, L., A.F. Fry, and J. Myerson. (1994). Discounting of delayed rewards: A life span comparison. Psychological Science, 5, 33-36. [Google Scholar]
  21. Herrnstein, Richard J., and Drazen Prelec. (1992). A Theory of Addiction. In: Choice Over Time. George Loewenstein and Jon Elster, eds. New York, NY: Russel Sage Foundation. [Google Scholar]
  22. Holcomb, James H. and Paul S. Nelson. (1992). Another Experimental Look at Individual Time Preference. Rationality and Society, 4(2), 199-220. [Google Scholar]
  23. Horowitz, John K. (1991). Discounting Money Payoffs: An Experimental Analysis. In: Handbook of Behavioral Economics (Volume 2B). Greenwich, CT.: JAI Press. [Google Scholar]
  24. Johnson, Richard E., Anastasios C. Marcos, and Stephen J. Bahr. (1987). The Role of Peers in the Complex Etiology of Adolescent Drug Use. Criminology, 25(2), 323-340. [Google Scholar]
  25. Johnstone, J.W.C. (1983). Recruitment to a Youth Gang. Youth and Society, 14, 281-300. [Google Scholar]
  26. Kalett, Ethan G. (1996). Twelve Steps, You’re Out (Of Prison): An Evaluation of “Anonymous Programs” as Alternative Sentences. Hastings Law Journal, 48, 129-165. [Google Scholar]
  27. Kirby, Kris N., Nancy M. Petry, and Warren K. Bickel. (1999). Heroin Addicts Have Higher Discount [Google Scholar]
  28. Rates for Delayed Rewards Than Non-Drug-Using Controls. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 128(1), 78-87. [Google Scholar]
  29. Klochko, Marianna. (2008). Individual time preferences in prison population: the effects of rehabilitation programs on women vs. men in Ukraine. In: Beyond Little Vera: Women’s Bodies, Women’s Welfare in Russia and Central/Eastern Europe, pp.185-206. Angela Brintlinger and Natasha Kolchevska, eds. Columbus, OH: Ohio Slavic Papers. [Google Scholar]
  30. Klochko, Marianna (2006). Time Preferences and Learning versus Selection: A Case Study of Ukrainian Students. Rationality and Society, 18(3), 305-331. [Google Scholar]
  31. Klochko, Marianna and Peter C. Ordeshook. (2005). Endogenous Time Preferences in Social Networks. Cheltonham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited. [Google Scholar]
  32. Kolstad, Arnulf. (1996). Imprisonment as rehabilitation: Offenders’ assessment of why it does not work. Journal of Criminal Justice, 24(4), 323-335. [Google Scholar]
  33. Loewenstein, George F. and Drazen Prelec. (1993). Preferences for Sequences of Outcomes. Psychological Review, 100(1), 91-108. [Google Scholar]
  34. Madden, G. J., N.M. Petry, W.K. Bickel, and G.J. Badher. (1997). Impulsive and self-control choices in opiate-dependent patients and non-drug-using control participants: Drug and monetary rewards. Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology, 5, 63-83. [Google Scholar]
  35. McAuliffe, William E., Jeff Albert, Georgia Cordill-London, and Thomas K. McGarraghy. (1990-91). Contributions to a Social Conditioning Model of Cocaine Recovery. The International Journal of the Addictions, 25(9A & 10A), 1141-1177. [Google Scholar]
  36. MacKillop, James and Christopher W. Kahler. (2009). Delayed reward discounting predicts treatment response for heavy drinkers receiving smoking cessation treatment. Drug and Alcohol Dependence, 104(3), 197-203. [Google Scholar]
  37. Mischel, Waletr, Yuichi Shoda, and Monica L. Rodriguez. (1992). Delay of Gratification in Children. In: Choice Over Time. George Loewenstein and Jon Elster, eds. New York, NY: Russel Sage Foundation. [Google Scholar]
  38. Nagin, Daniel S., and Greg Pogarsky. (2001). Integrating Celerity, Impulsivity, and Extralegal Sanction Threats into a Model of General Deterrence. Criminology, 39(4), 865- 892. [Google Scholar]
  39. Odum, Amy L., Gregory J. Madden, and Warren K. Bickel. (2002). Discounting of delayed health gains and losses by current, never- and ex-smokers of cigarettes. Nicotine and Tobacco Research, 4(3), 295-303. [Google Scholar]
  40. Olson, Mancur. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. New York, NY: Schocken Books. [Google Scholar]
  41. Skog, O.J. (1997). The Strength of Weak Will. Rationality and Society, 6(2), 245-269. [Google Scholar]
  42. Vuchinich, Rudy E. and Cathy A. Simpson. (1998). Hyperbolic Temporal Discounting in Social Drinkers and Problem Drinkers. Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology, 6(3), 292-305. [Google Scholar]
  43. Wilson, James Q., and R. J. Hernstein. (1985). Crime and Human Nature. New York, NY: Simon and Schuster. [Google Scholar]

Full metadata record

Cite this record

APA style

Klochko, Marianna (2015). The endogeneity of time preference and analysis of collective behavior. (2015). The endogeneity of time preference and analysis of collective behavior. Decyzje, (24), 107-122. https://doi.org/10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.63 (Original work published 12/2104AD)

MLA style

Klochko, Marianna. “The Endogeneity Of Time Preference And Analysis Of Collective Behavior”. 12/2104AD. Decyzje, no. 24, 2015, pp. 107-122.

Chicago style

Klochko, Marianna. “The Endogeneity Of Time Preference And Analysis Of Collective Behavior”. Decyzje, Decyzje, no. 24 (2015): 107-122. doi:10.7206/DEC.1733-0092.63.